I keep hearing from
some in the news commentary world that raising the minimum wage doesn't really
have any bad impact. Basically during this big promo of the President's, to
raise it from $7.25 to $10.10. That rising costs of labor, in the absence of
rising sales (read: during weak economic times like now), won't cause business
owners to find ways to recoup the lost profits. In my view, that's just fantasy,
irrespective of whatever Princeton study they want to cite. (But it is a popular vote-getter or
poll-booster.)
Below, is a real-world
example walk-through of business expenses, using a generic restaurant business.
It’s lengthy, but maybe informative for those who are not business owners and
don’t think about this stuff every day.
But before that, just some
basic facts, because there's a lot of spin out there. The current minimum wage
is $7.25/hr. Using the CPI Index, adjusting for inflation, it has averaged
$7.13 since its inception in 1938. So it is in line with inflation, as defined
by the CPI index. (I have my beef with CPI being a good gauge of inflation, but
that’s another battle.)
The current poverty
level for individuals is about a $15 thousand annual income. Adjusted for
inflation, it has always been $15 thousand. ~$7.13-7.25/hr, 40 hours per week,
52 weeks per year is ~$14.8-15 thousand annually.
So minimum wage has
been historically designed to cover you up to the poverty level. It is not
presently lagging. It is in line. To say
that wages have been flat, “when adjusted for inflation”, as they have for the
past few decades before the effects of the financial crisis is to say that wages have increased at the same rate as
inflation.
Having said that, from
1961 through 1979, minimum wage was somewhere in the zip code of ~$9/hr, adjusted for
inflation. In other words, it provided almost ~$4 thousand more annually in
today’s dollars over the poverty level during that time. That's what the
Administration is advocating presently - a minimum wage that offers more than
the poverty level.
I am not judging. I am
not saying it is too low or too high. I am actually for raising it, but only
when the economy is stronger. Benchmarking a raise in the minimum wage when
say, unemployment declines to a certain level. That way everybody wins. Lower
incomes get a raise; and businesses have more profits from higher sales to pay
them, continue to expand and still compensate owners for their risk-taking.
But most importantly,
it incentivizes all of us to come up with ways to improve the economy, rather
than instead to come up with ways to simply offer greater reward for doing
nothing more than what you are already doing. The latter being the bane of all
heretofore class struggle.
In my view, if we want
to fight stagnant wages, we need to encourage public-private partnerships to
incubate nascent technologies and grow them into 21st Century
industries and markets that will pay a higher wage. We need to invest in education to align it to
preparing our workers for those industries.
Part of that fight involves checking what has been runaway education
inflation.
Our wages are low,
because we keep trying to compete too often in markets that, now places like
China, Brazil, India, the Philippines are developing more and more skilled
labor that is still willing to work for half or less what the average American
might. That international pressure –
available only when markets are free to source labor at the best price – I
believe is the single largest pressure on all our incomes in the past few
decades. And that is an inevitable free
market force, as lesser nations grow in wealth and offer a more skilled, yet
still cheaper source of labor.
Not a weak union. Their only argument is for protectionism
really, which runs antithetical to healthy markets and ultimately just sickens
domestic industry v. foreign competition.
See how much better our auto industry is, now that we abrogated through
their financial crisis bankruptcies all those way-over-market benefits
packages, negotiated decades ago by the then-stronger unions?
Not evil big
business. They are operating freely as
market animals, sourcing the best possible labor at the best possible price
available globally. S&P 500 operating
profit margins right now are about 15%, a few points higher than the average of
the past few decades. But it just came
out of being a few points below that through the financial crisis. So they are basically historically in line
right now.
________________________________________________________________________
Real-world example of operating business results (using a generic restaurant in the US, based upon my experience doing diligence on thousands of operating companies over the years):
A little background - in the
US, restaurant sales represent about 4% of GDP and employ about 10% of the
workforce. About half of all dollar-food sales in the US are through
restaurants. All of us have had the experience of being a patron – so it’s
a familiar business model to use as an example.
Restaurants are the perfect
window into the small businesses that drive the US economy, and the classical
debate between lower income earning employees v. their risk-taking
entrepreneurial owner-employers. Restaurants are the typical American Dream,
as 80% of them are started by people who began at near minimum wage working in
that industry. So today’s low-wage
employee is highly likely to be tomorrow’s restaurant owner.
[For the following
discussion, please refer to the tables at the end.]
Average annual sales for a
restaurant in the US is about $700 thousand per unit. The cost of food
and liquor ranges ~25-35% and ~18-25% of sales, respectively. In the
sample income statement (below) I arrive at a 26.4% cost of sales for our
generic restaurant, which assumes that food is 55% of sales and costs 30%; liquor
is 45% of sales and costs 22%.
That leaves $515 thousand
gross profit to pay for everything else to operate. Most of everything
else is the cost of labor and the cost of occupancy. I’ll do labor last
because that’s the punch line, although it is typically a restaurant’s largest
operating expense.
First, cost of
occupancy. Take an average 2,500 square foot tenant establishment, where
20% is utility (kitchen, storage, office, eg.). That leaves 2,000 square
feet for patrons. The more successful restaurants generate ~$500-600 per
usable square foot. The typical “Mom and Pops”, more like ~$350 (which equals
our $700 thousand sales example).
Rent ranges from ~$25-45 per
square foot on average across the nation right now (but can be over $80 in
wealthy urban areas). Let’s use $35. That’s $88 thousand annually
in rent (which is triple net, including landlord property taxes, etc., as is
standard nowadays). Electric, gas and water utilities for premises like
this might consume about ~4-5% of sales in this current environment. I’m
using $30 thousand, or 4.3%.
So that’s $118 thousand of
fixed occupancy costs to take away from $515 thousand in gross profit. That leaves $398 thousand.
Now there’s the repair and
maintenance - or replacement - of all the various equipment, furniture and
fixtures. One stove might cost ~$4-10 thousand to replace. One
refrigerator, freezer or dishwasher, ~$3-6 thousand each. Ice bins, POS
systems, sinks, prep tables, exhaust systems ~$1-3 thousand each. If you
want to have TVs for entertainment, a number of large screens could quickly add
up to $10 thousand or more. Chairs, tables, booths, dishware…
A typical 2,500 square foot
place is going to easily have $80 to $120 thousand of stuff (likely
higher). Purchased by the business owner with their own savings.
That depreciates (depending on what it is) every three to seven years to almost
$0 salvage value. So depreciation expense - the proxy for the cost of
replacement - on $100 thousand of stuff then will be somewhere around ~$20
thousand per year in this example. That’s before repair and maintenance,
which can easily add up to another several thousand per year. Let’s call
that $5 thousand.
Now that leaves $373
thousand in profit available. There is a good-sized list of other stuff
that restaurants pay that absolutely adds up to a number. Liability
insurance, permits and licensing on something like this could be $5-7+ thousand
per year. Credit card fees, if you assume 60-80% of sales are with credit
cards can be $9-12 thousand on $700 thousand sales (Visa/Mastercard costs the
merchant ~1.8-2% of charged sales, AmEx ~3-4%+; not to mention the tip is usually
in that). Trash collection, security monitoring, cable/satellite (if you
have TVs are several thousand dollars a year), linen cleaning (super-expensive,
which is why you don’t often see tables clothes or linen napkins) and the
general expenses like phone, professional fees… all of that can very easily be
another ~4-7% of sales all added up. I am using $32 thousand, or 4.3% of
sales.
That basically covers
everything other than the cost of labor. Almost all of that other than
cost of sales is 100% fixed. Meaning, no
matter who does or does not walk through the door, you are paying that nut no
matter what. So we are now left with $339
thousand of that original $700 thousand to pay for the cost of its employees
and hopefully have something left over for the business owner that is taking
all the risk investing in and operating the business.
A place like this might have
a chef at $15/hr, an assistant cook at $9.50/hr, a prep cook at $8.50/hr, and a
couple busboy/expos at $7.50/hr. It
might also have a bartender and maybe three servers for a total of four tipped
hourly employees. The average of all 50
states and D.C. for minimum wages paid by the employer to tipped hourlies in
the food service industry, adjusting for an allowable tip credit, is $3.85/hr. Add to that a manager to keep everyone honest
and have someone for the patrons to yell at, and that’s possibly another $40
thousand to payroll annually. Making
certain assumptions then (see Table 1 below) all that labor adds up to $245
thousand annually.
But we’re not done on the
cost of labor. The employer owes a
contribution of payroll taxes on the base pay, plus all their declared
tips. In my example, this is another $28
thousand expense. Add a little for
workers’ comp, and total cost of labor here is $275 thousand, or 39.3% of
sales.
In this example, that leaves
$65 thousand of operating profit available to the owner. That’s 9.3% of sales, which is low in the
context that the more successful units can generate 12-25%. But, as most restaurant costs are fixed, that
greater success really comes largely from having a brand that brings in higher
traffic and allows you to charge higher prices for the same slop.
In this example, cost of
labor is at the higher end as a % of sales (40%) and can be as low as
mid-20%. But that involves serious labor
cuts that can eat into quality of service and possibly sales as a result, and/or
the owner assuming certain roles (manager or bartender for example) to cut
labor.
So
here’s the whole point.
This example uses the national average of $3.85/hr for a restaurant to
pay tipped hourlies (or more, as the restaurant must cover any shortfall if
their declared tips don’t get them to minimum wage). Pretend instead it had to operate in a state
where those costs were mandated by the government to be a lot higher. CT for example where I live, requires that
tipped hourly food servers be paid $5.69/hr, and bartenders $7.34/hr. If I rework Table 1, plugging in those
numbers, total cost of labor is now $308 thousand.
That’s $33 thousand higher
labor costs annually. With no additional
sales coming through the doors, now the owner of the business is only earning
$32 thousand. The person taking all the
risk and all the headache of running a business is now earning about what her
assistant cook is making. Which is kind
of out of whack. And in a business,
where a $3 reduction in average check or ~7-9 less patrons per day can wipe out
all profits to begin with, just the whiff of the government suggesting that
they will have to pay more for labor, will already chill hiring decisions.
Forced by the government to
pay everyone more on the same amount of sales, what do you think the owner is
going to do? Of course they’re going to cut hours or full-out let people
go. They sure-as-shinola aren’t going to take on another employee.
And all of that will now start eating into sales and quality of service.
Compromising the viability of the business. So they also do what most
restaurant owners do when they start to panic in the face of reducing profits –
raise menu prices. Which drives people to the place next door that
didn’t. Which just sends them quicker into a loss situation.
The President is currently
pushing raising the minimum wage by $2.85 from $7.25 to $10.10. If we raised all of this labor in this
example by the lesser of $2.85 or to the $10.10 threshold, that now makes the
total cost of labor $337 thousand. That
basically wipes out all profit to the owner in this example. And now the busboys are making what the
assistant chef and prep cook makes. You
think the kitchen isn’t going to be griping about wanting more than the busboys?
As the owner makes
adjustments to recoup lost profits, all of that adds up to a reduction of work
opportunity for employees, coming from the very thing that the government did trying
to help them in the first place – raising minimum wages in the absence of
improved sales for the business.
The counter-point suggests that that extra coin in workers' pockets is a direct stimulus to the economy. And it is. Just in nominal terms. When demand is not strong enough, the ultimate effect is just an increase in the price of everything, without an increase in output or real growth - read, staglation.
The counter-point suggests that that extra coin in workers' pockets is a direct stimulus to the economy. And it is. Just in nominal terms. When demand is not strong enough, the ultimate effect is just an increase in the price of everything, without an increase in output or real growth - read, staglation.
So to conclude, if you want
to raise this place’s cost of labor by ~$60 thousand without it having a
negative repercussion on work opportunity for its employees, then do it as the
restaurant is making at least $60 thousand more in profits. And none of
this is to support only the business owner and blame the employee. It's a
relationship, where both the employee and employer have legitimate
positions. The employee should be able to work full time and not live in
poverty. The employer is risking capital – often their life savings – and
deserves a significant compensation incentive for the risk during their
successful years.
No comments:
Post a Comment